Changing the tiger's stripes: Reform of Chinese state-owned enterprises in the penumbra of the state from buzai232's blog

Much of China’s economic growth has been driven by the emergence of a vibrant private sector, today accounting for approximately 60% of GDP and 80% of employment. To get more finance news in China, you can visit shine news official website.
Conventional wisdom holds that privatisation of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) reduces their dependence on the state and yields positive economic benefits including enhanced firm performance, productivity, and innovation. The pro-privatisation argument is that the state either cannot monitor managers properly or chooses not to pursue efficiency because state interests take precedence over financial results (Boardman and Vining 1989, Vickers and Yarrow 1991, Shleifer and Vishny 1994). Empirical work, however, has produced mixed results on privatisation. For example, DeWenter and Malatesta (2001) found that, among the 500 largest firms globally in 1975, 1985, and 1995, private enterprises had significantly lower costs and higher profits than SOEs. Yet, when they examined a sub-sample of privatised firms, they found inconsistent results – performance increased post-privatisation, while leverage and employment increased mainly pre-privatisation. Market returns from privatisation also differed across countries, positive in Hungary, Poland, and the UK but insignificant elsewhere.

Our research on privatisation in China (Harrison et al. 2019) is unique in several respects. We analyse an extremely large sample of industrial firms, more than 3.5 million firm-years from 1998 to 2013, drawing on the Annual Industrial Survey conducted by the China National Bureau of Statistics.1 We compare privatised firms with firms that remained state-owned and firms that had never been state-owned. Most importantly, we compare both the performance and dependence on the state of privatised firms with firms having no prior state ownership. Overall, our results indicate selective performance gains from privatisation – privatised firms have greater productivity and are more likely to file patents than firms remaining state-owned even though their return on assets barely improves. The performance effects notwithstanding, privatised firms remain dependent on the state. Subsidies, concessionary interest rates, and loans granted to privatised firms remain at nearly the same levels as those to SOEs. Privatisation changes the behaviour of firms but not firms’ dependence on the state.
Privatisation occurs when the state ceases to hold majority ownership and/or is no longer the controlling shareholder of a firm. A firm is considered state-owned if either 50% or more of its capital shares are owned by the state or the controlling shareholder is the state (in China, the controlling shareholder need not be the majority shareholder). When either of these conditions holds in year t, but neither holds in year t+1, a firm becomes privately owned.

In our analysis, we also separated firms with non-zero legal-person ownership from firms without legal-person owners to control for the possibility that legal-person ownership remains a disguised form of state control. We found no significant differences between firms with and without legal-person ownership. Our regression results, which are discussed in our paper, are based on models with multiple controls including trends for the pre- and post-2008 periods, and fixed effects for year, industry, and firm (industry and firm fixed effects are entered separately).

Previous post     
     Next post
     Blog home

The Wall

No comments
You need to sign in to comment